A little bit of this and that……

Collective Risk Dilemma

A collective-risk social dilemma arises when a group must cooperate to reach a common target in order to avoid the risk of collective loss while each individual is tempted to free-ride on the contributions of others. In contrast to

the prisoners' dilemma or public goods games, the collective-risk dilemma encompasses the risk that all individuals lose everything. These characteristics have potential relevance for dangerous climate change and other risky social

dilemmas. Climate change relief is truly the most influential cooperative act we can be a part of, especially since our decisions now may influence the decisions of future generations. However, collaborative prospects are disheartening due to the uncertainties associated with Climate change and the diversity of the actors involved (eg. wealth).  Cooperation is costly to the individual and it only benefits all individuals if the common target is reached.

An individual thus invests without guarantee that the investment is worthwhile for anyone. If there are several subsequent stages of investment, it is not clear when individuals should contribute. Thus, in this game, the timing of contributions becomes a strategic variable that allows individuals to interact and influence one another. We investigate the strategic behavior using an evolutionary model of such collective-risk dilemmas in a finite population; every individual takes part in many games and successful behaviors spread in the population. Individual contributions depend on the stage of the game and on the sum of contributions made so far. Thus far prediction have shown that, the best strategy was to `wait and see'.

This was consistent under homogeneity, heterogeneity, target uncertainty, across round number and various group sizes. However one key difference in heterogeneity, the rich players contribute in excess in oder to compensate for the missing contributions of the poor. 

Avian Host-Parasite Mafia Behaviour

Mafia like behavior, where individuals cooperate under the threat of punishment, occurs not only in humans, but is also observed in several animal species. Observations suggest that avian hosts tend to accept a certain degree of parasitism in order to avoid retaliating punishment from the brood parasite. To understand under which conditions it will be beneficial for a host to cooperate, we model the interaction between hosts and parasites as an evolutionary game. In our model, the host's behavior is plastic, and thus, its response depends on the previous interactions with the parasite. We find that such learned behavior in turn is crucial for the evolution of retaliating parasites. The abundance of this kind of mafia behavior oscillates in time and does not settle to an equilibrium. Our results suggest that retaliation is a mechanism for the parasite to evade specialisation and to induce acceptance by the host.

We model the interaction between hosts (e.g. magpies, Pica pica, and prothonotary warblers, Protonotaria citrea) and parasites (e.g. cuckoos, Clamator glandarius, and cowbirds, Molothrus ater) as an evolutionary game. These species tend to interact with each other over several seasons. In each season a parasite can lay more than a single egg in the host’s nest without fear that the parasite nestling will evict its siblings out of the nest; both the young of the host and parasite  are raised together 1, 12, 22 . Thus, in this system there are repeated interactions within a breeding  season. We classify the host-parasite interactions into four stages: (i) During the first parasitism stage the parasite lays a certain number of eggs in the nest and the host will choose to accept these  eggs or to reject them. (ii) If the host rejects, the parasite could depredate and destroy the host’s nest during the first depredation stage. This stage occurs after the host rejects, which could be any time between egg laying and nestling hatching 12. (iii) The second parasitism occurs only when the parasite returns to the same host to lay additional eggs after rejection or after the host reclutches.  (iv) The second depredation stage occurs after a host rejects the returning parasite. 

shapeimage 3

Theoretical Morphology

shapeimage 2

Echinoids have an endoskeletal system which is ideal for studying calcified structures such as development of vertebrate skeletons. However, understanding echinoid skeletal (test) growth has proven challenging to analyse solely on the basis of any one approach or process. Therefore, theoretical models have been developed to understand growth and form of echinoid tests. Herein, Holotestoid, a computational model of echinoid test growth is described. The model incorporates mathematical principles (e.g., close-packing), physical principles (e.g., interface between coalescing bubbles) and biological processes (e.g., echinoid ontogenic processes). It is the first computational model that emulates all five ontogenic processes involved in test growth (plate growth, plate addition, plate interaction, plate gapping, and visceral growth) using a geometrical representation and three analogies (coalescing bubble, circle-packing, and catenary chains). The emulated processes are used to predict plate size, plate shape, and test shape.



Size-Assortative Mating

Size-assortative mating is a nonrandom  association of body size between members of mating  pairs and  is expected to  be common  in  species with mutual preferences for body size. In this  study, we investigated whether there is direct evidence for  size-assortative mating  in  two  species of  pipefishes,  Syngnathus floridae and S. typhle, that share the characteristics of male pregnancy, sex-role reversal, and a polygynandrous mating system. We take advantage of microsatellite-based “genetic-capture”  techniques  to  match  wild-caught  females with female genotypes reconstructed  from broods  of pregnant  males and  use these data  to  explore patterns  of size-assortative mating  in  these species. We also develop a simulation model to  explore how positive, negative, and antagonistic preferences of each sex for body size affect size-assortative  mating. Contrary to expectations, we were unable to find any evidence of size-assortative mating in either species  at different geographic locations or at different sampling times. Furthermore,  two traits that  potentially confer  a  fitness advantage in terms of reproductive success, female mating order and number  of eggs transferred per female, do not affect pairing patterns in the wild. Results from model simula- tions  demonstrate  that  strong  mating  preferences are unlikely to  explain the observed patterns of mating in the studied populations.  Our  study shows that individual mating preferences, as ascertained by laboratory-based mating trials, can be  decoupled  from realized patterns of mating in the wild, and therefore, field studies are also necessary to  determine actual patterns of mate choice in nature.  We conclude that  this disconnect between preferences and  assortative mating  is likely due  to  ecological constraints  and  multiple  mating  that  may limit mate choice in natural populations.


© Maria Abou Chakra 2015